E-Book, Englisch, Band Volume 7, 320 Seiten
Smith The Sea of Lost Opportunity
1. Auflage 2011
ISBN: 978-0-444-53646-4
Verlag: Elsevier Science & Techn.
Format: EPUB
Kopierschutz: 6 - ePub Watermark
North Sea Oil and Gas, British Industry and the Offshore Supplies Office
E-Book, Englisch, Band Volume 7, 320 Seiten
Reihe: Handbook of Petroleum Exploration and Production
ISBN: 978-0-444-53646-4
Verlag: Elsevier Science & Techn.
Format: EPUB
Kopierschutz: 6 - ePub Watermark
This book is a contribution to the history of a vital stage of UK technical and economic development, perhaps the most important since the Second World War. It shows, from an industrial viewpoint, how the British handled the exploitation of their most significant natural resource gain of the 20th century. Notwithstanding the nearly 30 years of government support through the Offshore Supplies Office, the UK has not reaped the full benefit of the North Sea discoveries; this book attempts to explain why. It will assist governments and industries faced with future instances of unforeseen, specialist and large-scale new demand to manage their reactions more effectively. It also throws light on how governments can pursue strategic industrial objectives while leaving market mechanisms to function with minimal interference, something some administrations - perhaps even the British - may wish to do now or in the future. - Covers the entire period from the first well offshore Britain until the dismantling of the specific British industrial policy measures for offshore supplies - Based in large measure upon archives not previously accessed and the private testimony/papers of participants - 'Drills down' to the level of individual company decisions through case study and other material - The only properly researched description of how the world's first major local content initiative developed
Norman Smith holds degrees from Oxford University (M.A.), the City University (M. Phil.) and Aberdeen University (Ph.D.). He has also participated in development programmes at Harvard and INSEAD/CEDEP. He is a Fellow of the Energy Institute and of the Society of Business Economists. His career began in engineering manufacture where he first became involved with the offshore oil and gas industry. After a spell in merchant banking, he was seconded to the Department of Energy. On his return to the private sector, he co-founded and managed an energy consulting company, Smith Rea Energy Associates Ltd (SREA) , and served as director of eight private companies in the oil and gas industry, becoming chairman of three. After retirement, he researched and authored this extensive study of the British supply chain supporting exploration and production activities in the North Sea: The Sea of Lost Opportunity: North Sea Oil and Gas, British Industry and the Offshore Supplies Office. He felt it was important that the story of this extraordinary episode in British economic and technological history should be chronicled by somebody who had been closely involved in it and that he was well qualified to undertake the task. Though now formally retired, he continues to write and would always consider a speaking engagement or even a tantalisingly interesting piece of advisory work. His website is http://normanjsmith.wordpress.com/
Autoren/Hrsg.
Weitere Infos & Material
1;Front Cover;1
2;The Sea of Lost Opportunity: North Sea Oil and Gas, British Industry and the Offshore Supplies Office;4
3;Copyright;5
4;Dedication;6
5;Contents;8
6;List of Tables;10
7;List of Charts;11
8;List of Figures;12
9;Acknowledgements;14
10;Preface;16
11;Chapter 1: In Europe's Sick Bay;22
11.1;1.1. The british balance of payments problem;23
11.2;1.2. Oil and the balance of payments;25
11.3;1.3. British economic and industrial decline;31
11.4;1.4. An insufficient inheritance: the british oilfield supply industry;40
12;Chapter 2: The Genesis of the North Sea Oil and Gas Industry;44
12.1;2.1. The move to the north sea;45
12.2;2.2. The technological `state of the art´;47
12.3;2.3. The united kingdom position;57
12.4;2.4. Potential european competitors;71
12.5;2.5. Perceptions of the ukcs hydrocarbon resource base;74
12.6;2.6. The new technical challenges of the north sea;77
13;Chapter 3: Motivations and Constraints;82
13.1;3.1. The exploration and production companies;82
13.2;3.2. The british government;90
13.3;3.3. British industry;101
13.4;3.4. Finance;106
14;Chapter 4: Before OSO: Offshore Supplies 1963-1972;114
14.1;4.1. Oil company attitudes to british suppliers;115
14.2;4.2. Government attitudes to british suppliers;118
14.3;4.3. The imeg report;119
14.4;4.4. An assessment of the period;121
15;Chapter 5: OSO's Formative Years 1973-1980;130
15.1;5.1. The course of demand;131
15.2;5.2. OSO operations in context;132
15.3;5.3. OSO and the machinery of government;135
15.4;5.4. Some key OSO issues of the period;138
15.5;5.5. The supply industry;162
16;Chapter 6: OSO's Long March into History 1981-1993;190
16.1;6.1. The course of demand;194
16.2;6.2. OSO operations in context;195
16.3;6.3. Some key OSO issues of the period;196
16.4;6.4. The supply industry;207
17;Chapter 7: Assessing OSO;224
17.1;7.1. Third-party commentary;224
17.2;7.2. One insider's view;229
17.3;7.3. OSO's statistics;233
17.4;7.4. A summing-up;236
18;Chapter 8: Case Studies and Expert Testimony;240
18.1;8.1. Market segment case studies;240
18.2;8.2. Corporate case studies;246
18.3;8.3. Expert testimony;259
19;Chapter 9: Looking Back on a 30-Year Journey;268
19.1;9.1. Some propositions;268
19.2;9.2. Some conclusions;274
19.3;9.3. Could it have been otherwise?;277
20;Chapter 10: Postscript;286
20.1;10.1. The UKCS oil and gas industry and its supply sector today;287
20.2;10.2. What of the future?;295
21;Source Materials;304
22;Glossary;314
23;Index;322
Chapter 1 In Europe’s Sick Bay
Britain before North Sea Oil
Norman J. Smith Abstract
This chapter ‘sets the scene’ in terms of the difficult UK Economic and Industrial Environment prior to the discovery of offshore oil and the expectations the latter engendered. The questions of how to catalyse a British offshore supply industry and to measure the effectiveness of government policy are raised. Keywords
economic difficulties; industrial decline; balance of payments; major projects; supply sector Although it may seem strange to devote the opening pages of a book about the North Sea offshore oil and gas industry to broad economic and industrial issues, it is important to do so. Appreciating the circumstances and perceptions of the time offers the prospect of an insight into the mind-sets of those who made the policy decisions 50 or so years ago. When the offshore industry reached the United Kingdom (UK) in the 1960s, the country already had a well-developed industrial base and much prior experience in the exploitation of oil and gas. It was the domicile of some of the world’s largest exploration and production companies. At the same time the British economy was facing considerable difficulties. It was inflexible in character – a result of government industrial policies, poor management, entrenched trade union power and a scarcity of venture capital. Governments became increasingly pre-occupied with a range of negative economic indicators such as balance of payment deficits, the public finances, poor productivity growth, strikes, increasing unemployment and rising inflation. There was a widespread perception that Britain was in relative economic decline. It became commonplace to speak of the combination of negative trends in terms of a ‘British disease’, which – unless cured – would condemn the UK to grow at a slower rate than its peers. The long-term outlook appeared to be one of over-extension and continued relative decline, with short-term policy driven by the balance of payments and exchange rate considerations. Inevitably, once it became clear that this newly arrived industry was likely to add a significant increment to the nation’s resources and to make its most substantial impact by easing the balance of payments constraint, it became the focus of political attention. This attention was to be heightened by the hope that substantial economic benefits would flow to the areas closest to the oil and gas fields, many characterised by declining heavy industries and rising unemployment. From the early 1970s, government concern over security of oil supply – shared by the oil companies, whose interests were otherwise purely commercial – added another powerful driver. Whilst there are grounds to criticise British government policies towards the offshore supplies industry, such criticisms need to recognise that, in addition to immediate crises such as the 1972 and 1974 coal miners’ strikes and the 1973 oil price hike, governments were heavily constrained by what were seen at the time as long-term economic problems of a structural nature. For investors in what was from the outset a costly and risky endeavour, having to address the high expectations of the government and the public whilst seeking to meet their own business objectives was challenging. It was not made easier by the fact that the very British industries to which it would be natural to turn to as suppliers, such as shipbuilding and major capital project construction, were clearly already facing great difficulties. 1.1 The british balance of payments problem
In the then world of fixed exchange rates and with the pound sterling still having the status of a reserve currency for many of the UK’s former dependencies, the most pressing of the constraints faced by British governments was usually the balance of payments. The balance of payments was thus commonly perceived as the main ‘driver’ of short-term government economic policy. Thus, the importance of the shift from being a net oil importer to being a net exporter, which followed the development of the United Kingdom Continental Shelf (UKCS), should not be underestimated, particularly because it also brought security of oil supply and increased government revenues in its wake. During the period from 1947 to 1976, Kirby (1991, p. 23) recognised no less than eight cycles of boom and slump, a pattern that became known as the ‘stop–go’ cycle. Two of these, 1964–1967 and 1973–1976, respectively, saw the genesis of the British offshore gas industry and the most active phase of British offshore oil development. Conditions in both these periods were ‘extreme’ in terms of factors other than their protracted length, with correspondingly ‘extreme’ implications for government policy. The first was characterised by a perceived speculative severity that led to sterling devaluation in November 1967, although the current account was actually close to balance (Thirwall and Gibson 1992, p. 238). The second period, during which the pound sterling was already floating freely, combined a domestic crisis with the international one that followed the Yom Kippur War of 1973, the associated steep increase in oil prices and the Arab oil embargo. At home, a government lacking a clear Parliamentary majority faced industrial unrest, a depreciating currency and rising inflation. On this occasion, the British government was unable to contain the crisis by its own efforts. In June 1976, it was announced that a Group of Ten Nations had loaned it $5.3 billion (Thirwall and Gibson p. 249), roughly $16.2 billion in 2008 terms. This loan formed part of Britain’s growing medium- and long-term foreign currency borrowings, which by November 1976 totalled about $18.5 billion (Arnold 1978, p. 327), over $56.5 billion in 2008 values. Accumulated mainly in the previous 3 years, with the main repayments falling due in the 1980s when it was believed North Sea oil production would be at its peak, even this level of borrowing did not prove sufficient. At the end of the year Britain provided the International Monetary Fund (IMF) with a Letter of Intent containing commitments about the conduct of economic policy. In return, the IMF and the Group of Ten granted the country standby credits of $3.5 billion, or some $10.7 billion in 2008 terms, although these facilities never needed to be fully implemented (Wass 2008, p. 306). Typically, balance of payment crises brought periods of economic expansion to a premature end through interest rate increases and associated fiscal and monetary tightening; sometimes more direct action was taken, such as the imposition of the import surcharge in October 1964. The resultant contraction in domestic demand reduced imports and took the pressure off the exchange rate without the need – except in 1949 and 1967 – to devalue the pound sterling. Even after the pound was floated in 1972, the fear of a deteriorating balance of payments being followed by the inflationary consequences of a weakening exchange rate was slow to disappear. Although the improvement in the balance of payments permitted the reversal of the ‘stop’ measures and the resumption of ‘go’, the cycle reduced the long-term rate of economic growth and the productive potential of the UK because, in the view of Pollard (1984), the reduction of demand during ‘stop’ phases bore particularly hard on investment expenditure. Pollard saw the origins of the ‘stop–go’ cycle in the legacy of Britain’s position as a victorious power in 1945. The government itself was responsible, in his view, because of its slowness to adjust to Britain’s reduced status in the post-war world when it ceased to be a global imperial power, leading to at least two pretensions. The first was the maintenance during the period of fixed exchange rates of the Sterling Area, an arrangement through which countries – mainly former British dependencies and including a number of oil producers – used sterling as their international trading currency and held their foreign exchange reserves in London in the form of Sterling Balances. Although it need not always have worked to Britain’s disadvantage, commentators such as Pollard mainly regarded the existence of the Sterling Area and sterling’s status as an international trading currency as sources of weakness, amplifying cyclical balance of payment problems and constraining exchange rate policy by making the maintenance of a fixed parity a guiding principle of economic strategy. The second was the government’s own expenditure abroad on military expenses, foreign aid, and the servicing of overseas loans required to finance earlier deficits. In this analysis, the underlying cause of the balance of payments problem lay in the inability of the private sector to generate sufficiently large surpluses to finance the official sector’s overseas deficits. Pollard (1992, p. 307) noted the total private balance was in surplus in every individual year between 1961 and 1970. Overall, its surplus for the decade totalled £6.45 billion. By contrast, the total current government balance was in deficit in every individual year and accumulated a total deficit for the decade of £6.14 billion. The position deteriorated in the next decade. Between 1971 and 1980 the total private balance was in deficit in three of the 10 years, although it returned a cumulative surplus of £17.44 billion. The total current government balance remained in deficit in...